Climate PolicyClimate DividendDividend in detailEndorsersSupport

The Climate Dividend, in detail

Facts for policy wonks & everyday Aussies 🤓

“It is the sort of policy that politicians who believe in both the realities of climate change as well as the power and benefits of markets ought to support.”

One price on carbon

  • Producers would pay a fee on the carbon content of fossil fuels wherever they enter the economy, the mine, well, or port.

    It would start at A$50 per ton of CO2 and increase from there. The rising fee gives a powerful incentive to industry, consumers and investors to choose low to zero carbon alternatives.

    This approach is considered by most economists the fastest and most effective means to decarbonise our world.

  • Generally, “carbon tax” and “carbon fee” are used interchangeably, and refer to a similar type of legislation.

    Technically speaking, a tax has the primary purpose of raising revenue for the government. By contrast, a fee is a payment in exchange for a service or privilege.

    When the money raised is returned as a dividend, the policy is ‘revenue-neutral’ and does not grow the size of government.

  • Climate Dividends were introduced in Canada in 2018 and have already survived an election in which climate and carbon pricing were high on the agenda. The Greenhouse Gas Pollution Pricing Act 2018 provides a climate dividend to three Canadian provinces and territories and levies a fee on fossil fuels to support it. So now every province of Canada has some form of carbon price.

    British Columbia introduced a carbon fee in 2008 which does not pay a dividend but does recycle 100% of the revenue through tax cuts and concessions to low-income families. Emissions have reduced significantly and the economy has out-performed all other Canadian Provinces.

    Austria implemented climate dividends on the 1st of July 2022, calling it their Climate Bonus.

    A climate dividend bill, the Energy Innovation and Carbon Dividend Act is currently before the United States Congress. If passed, it will provide carbon dividends and rapidly decarbonise the US economy.

    Australia’s own carbon price, the Clean Energy Act 2011, recycled much of the revenue. Much of the revenue was recycled to households, but not in a way that enabled citizens to easily see how they were benefiting. Emissions reduced significantly while it was in place and rose when it was repealed. The economy grew at 2.6% /year while it was in place.

    Many jurisdictions have various forms of carbon pricing. You can find out more at the Carbon Pricing Leadership Coalition’s dashboard.

  • Placing a predictably-rising fee on carbon is less confusing to administer than cap-and-trade. It covers all fossil fuel-derived emissions, no matter how large or small. It avoids price volatility, market manipulation, and the need to monitor smokestacks. It also lends itself to policy alignment between nations.

    A longer explanation can be found here: citizensclimatelobby.org/laser-talks/carbon-fee-vs-cap-trade/

  • In the case of petrol or diesel, for example, each $1 per tonne increase in the carbon fee would mean a rise of about a 0.25 cents on the price of one litre of petrol. So, if the carbon fee started at $15 per tonne and rose by $10 per year, petrol would go up by about 5 cents per litre the first year and slightly over 3 cents each year thereafter.

    Electricity produced from fossil fuels will also rise with the fee. Renewable energy will not be affected and will become relatively cheaper over time. Gas prices will also rise.

More studies on pricing carbon at CCL USA: citizensclimatelobby.org/carbon-pricing-studies/

Dividends for everyone!

  • It’s also known as ‘climate income’ – money in the bank to support households in a decarbonising economy.

    Put simply, it is a monthly deposit in Aussies’ bank accounts derived from the fee on the carbon content of fossil fuels. It is paid in equal shares to all eligible Aussies.

    It is the simplest way to put the real costs of fossil fuels into prices without penalising citizens who are already paying increasing costs in terms of their health, and the mounting costs of extreme weather and environmental damage to our society.

    More info here: citizensclimatelobby.org/laser-talks/carbon-dividend-distribution/

  • First, simplicity: Transferring money from fossil fuel companies to the Australian people is easy to understand as the money doesn’t go into government coffers. Simpler policies like this have a higher level of integrity.

    Second, political will: Receiving cash in the bank every month means people across the political spectrum will feel more inclined to support the policy.

    Third, effectiveness: A dividend enables the price to rise high enough to drive emissions down fast enough to be effective. This could be as high as $200/tonne. Without a dividend, governments will have to keep the price much lower than this for fear of seriously disadvantaging a large portion of the population.

  • No. The net benefit for each household will depend on its reliance on carbon-intensive products. Put simply, low-income households would be better off, the average household would gain. Only households who use a lot of carbon would be worse off.

    In the 2018 paper linked above, Prof. R. Holden and R. Dixon from UNSW modelled the effect of a climate dividend on Australian society. They found that three-quarters of households will gain from the scheme. Moreover, the economic benefits were found to be the highest for households in the lowest income bracket.

    The dividend ensures that those least able to afford the transition are able to participate in decarbonising their economy.

  • Yes! A particular carbon fee and dividend scenario has been modelled by UNSW and presented as the Australian Climate Dividend Plan. In the United States, a comprehensive study was undertaken by Regional Economic Models, Inc. (REMI) and found that under a carbon fee and dividend scheme:

    • Carbon emissions from fossil energy would decline 33% after 10 years, and 52% after 20 years, relative to 1990 levels;

    • Economic activity would be stimulated by 5% over ‘business as usual;

    • 66% of people would be better off financially.

    • 100% of low- and middle-income households would be better off financially.

    With 100% of net revenue returned to households and a significant majority of consumers coming out ahead of rising costs, people would have more disposable income, which would encourage spending, stimulate the economy and expand total investment in the energy economy.

  • Between about 2007 and 2008 there was a degree of bipartisan political support for carbon pricing in Australia. Following the defeat of the Carbon Trading Scheme in 2008, carbon pricing and climate policy was politicised, and the parliament and nation became divided. The failure of the CoP climate conference in Copenhagen to reach agreement made it harder to maintain unity in Australia.

    The Clean Energy Act of 2012 implemented a carbon price that was quickly repealed after a divisive election and a change of government.

    In the meantime, other nations continued to introduce various forms of carbon pricing.

    The Paris Agreement of 2015 created increased momentum for climate policy and for carbon pricing, including in China. The revolution in renewable energy technology and its rapid uptake have made mainstream business and the general community more supportive of reform.

    Unfortunately, the climate dividend was unknown in 2008 when carbon pricing was being debated. A dividend paid to households would have gone some way to bridging the partisan divide and would have been difficult to repeal. The climate dividend is simple and transparent and people are more likely to understand it’s benefits, for themselves as well as for environment and economy. Prominent US conservative, Ted Halstead, called it “A Climate Solution Where All Sides Can Win

    The climate dividend recycles 100% of the revenue back into the economy via the monthly dividend paid to households. In the US, REMI modelling found that two-thirds of households would be financially better off if a climate dividend were implemented. Similar modelling by the University of NSW found that three-quarters of Australians would benefit from an Australian climate dividend.

    In 2017, 84 members of the US Congress – 50% Democrats and 50% Republicans formed a Climate Solutions Caucus, with CCL support. The Caucus strived to foster respectful bipartisan dialogue to help solve dilemmas of climate and energy policy. CCL helped establish the Parliamentary Friends of Climate Action for the same purpose.

    The climate dividend has enormous potential to generate bipartisan support for carbon pricing. Bipartisanship is vital if we are to enact an effective and durable climate policy – now an important expectation of the business community, who are already pricing carbon internally and calling for a carbon price through industry bodies like the Business Councils of Australia and the Australian Industry Group.

Border adjustment

  • A: It’s a mechanism that creates a level playing field between nations.

    Border adjustments put a price on the carbon content of goods and services at international borders. This is to ensure equity between countries and to enable carbon pricing to operate globally.

    The EU intends to introduce its Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM) for this purpose in 2024. Other major economies are likely to follow suit.

  • A: No. A Carbon Fee and Dividend scheme includes a Carbon Border Adjustment (CBA) to ensure competitiveness and protect business from unfair competition from countries without a carbon price. [source]. Products imported from a country without an equivalent carbon price would attract a surcharge or fee to make up the difference. Conversely, an Australian-made product exported to such a country would attract a rebate from the carbon fees fund held by the Australian Government equivalent to the carbon fee associated with the product’s carbon footprint.

    The CBA would prevent Australian manufacturers from being placed at a competitive disadvantage in global markets because of the carbon fee. It would remove the incentive for them to relocate overseas to avoid such a fee, and thereby prevent ‘carbon leakage’. In addition, it would encourage foreign countries to adopt their own carbon fee so that they would collect the money instead of us. It complies with the laws of international trade laid down in the GATT and administered by the WTO.

Simple regulation

  • Carbon pricing requires legislation to enable the regulation of carbon emissions, preferably at the national level. Such legislation would put a fee on carbon dioxide equivalents attributable to the use and extraction of fossil fuels. This fee would be assessed at the fuel’s source: the mine, well or port of entry. The fee would start out low and rise annually in a predictable manner until Australia reaches a ‘climate-safe’ level of emissions – 90% below 1990 levels.

    The fee would be collected at source and all fees collected, minus administrative costs, would then be reimbursed directly to all Australian households. This would shield them from the financial impact of the shift to a cleaner energy economy. Their spending will stimulate the economy towards increasingly cheaper low carbon activity and make high carbon activity increasingly expensive. This enables citizens to participate in decarbonising the economy by spending on low carbon alternatives. .

    Because the fee and the price of fossil fuels would go up predictably over time, CFD would send a clear price signal to investors, consumers, businesses, and the wider economy to:

    • Use fossil fuels more efficiently;

    • Replace fossil fuels with low- or zero-emissions energy;

    • Invest in low-emissions technologies; and

    • Bring the true cost of fossil fuels onto the balance sheet.

    This would:

    • Internalise the social costs of fossil fuels into their price, thus phasing out the implicit subsidies that derive from fossil fuels being allowed to pollute for free

    • Increase the demand for low-emissions products, making them increasingly more affordable;

    • Drive growth in the new economy;

    • Reduce greenhouse gas emissions, thus stabilising the climate, improving human health and restoring the health of the oceans.

  • No. Collecting a fee from fossil fuel producers and importers would be a relatively simple as the number of companies affected is fairly small. The costs of collecting and administering fee and dividend would be paid out of the fees collected.

  • Yes. By returning the net revenue back to households — the end-users — consumers would be able to pay the higher prices of goods and services caused by the higher price of fossil fuels. This would allow businesses to pass on their increased costs and maintain their market share.

    Each year that the carbon tax increased, the dividend would rise as well. Everyone would be on a level playing field for the first few years. But if businesses failed to become more energy-efficient and failed to reduce their emissions, they would become less competitive and lose market share.

    Market forces would therefore drive innovations in low-emissions technology, creating new business opportunities to develop, produce, install and service these products. This would create thousands of new jobs here in Australia. Companies would be able to sell these technologies globally and become more energy-efficient themselves, thereby becoming more competitive worldwide.

  • The clear price signal provided by the Climate Dividend would drive many of the changes that currently require complex legislation and regulation at higher cost. It will enable the market forces to make the many choices needed to decarbonise our economy. It will enable an orderly phase out of many high carbon products and services and enable business and consumers alike to transition with minimal regulation and funding.

    For example, the electrification of transport, heating and cooling, and industrial production will occur naturally due to market forces. Fossil fuels will phase out relatively smoothly as renewables become more abundant. Fossil fuel companies will be able to reinvest in low- or zero-carbon activities and avoid the high risk of crashing as the economy decarbonises around them. It will also reduce the risk of Australia being left with stranded assets.

    A Climate Dividend would provide a firm foundation for the many complementary policies that will be required to decarbonise our economy. For instance, the Safeguard Mechanism, designed to reduce industrial emissions, will be less onerous because the fossil fuel component of their emissions will have been priced at source. The mechanism can therefore focus on non-fuel related emissions such as those that come from cement production.

    Some less efficient polices will become redundant. The Emissions Reduction Fund which uses taxpayer dollars to buy carbon abatement from emitters would no longer be necessary. Risky carbon offsets would become less necessary and carbon removal technologies can be dedicated to mopping historical emissions instead of offsetting current ones.

    State governments have provided most of Australia’s decarbonisation polices in recent years. They will be able to re-evaluate their programs and drop or amend the ones that would be covered by the Climate Dividend. This will free them up to focus on the ‘hard to abate’ parts of their economies.

    Importantly, the Climate Dividend would enable Australia to decarbonise ahead of its Paris Agreement schedule and take a leading role in the global race to zero emissions.


Need even more information?

There’s a bunch of well-researched, short pages about climate dividends on CCL USA’s website.
Much of the information applicable to one country is applicable to all:

Building political will 🤝

The world is getting excited about carbon dividends!

 

Efficiency

Putting a price on carbon is cheap and hard to corrupt.

Popularity

The dividend is revenue-neutral, so it doesn’t increase taxes.

Fairness

The average Aussie will be better off under the climate dividend.

Choice

Everyone can make choices about how they spend their dividend.

 

Find your personal power, have a yarn with your local member of parliament.